Thursday, July 25, 2024

Real GDP grew at an annual rate of 2.8% in the 2nd quarter even though it was only expected to grow 2.1%

Only economists can probably get so excited about 0.7%. I will explain below. See U.S. economy grew at a 2.8% pace in the second quarter, much faster than expected by Jeff Cox of CNBC. Excerpt:

"Real gross domestic product, a measure of all the goods and services produced during the April-through-June period, increased at a 2.8% annualized pace adjusted for seasonality and inflation. Economists surveyed by Dow Jones had been looking for growth of 2.1% following a 1.4% increase in the first quarter.

Consumer spending helped propel the growth number higher, as did contributions from private inventory investment and nonresidential fixed investment.

Personal consumption expenditures, the main proxy in the Bureau of Economic Analysis report for consumer activity, increased 2.3% for the quarter, up from the 1.5% acceleration in Q1. Both services and goods spending saw solid increases for the quarter."

That might not seem like a big deal, just 0.7% more than expected. In my macro courses we read a chapter in the book The Economics of Macro Issues. The chapter discussed how nations with common law systems, where property rights are better protected than in nations with civil law systems, have higher growth rates. I pointed out to my classes that even a small difference in growth rates ends up causing a very big difference in per capita incomes due to the annual compounding effect.

The table below shows how much per capita income would be at various rates after 100 and 200 years. Assume we start with a per capita income of $1,000. If we grow 2.0% per year, after 100 years it will be $7,245. At 2.1% per year, it would be $7,791 or about $700 more. That is how much that little .1% matters. The difference over 200 years is about $11,000. After 100 years at 2.5% per year, per capita income would be $11,814. That is $4,000 more than the 2.0% rate. Small differences in growth rates add up to big differences over time.

Using the latest GDP figures for another example, if we grow 2.8% a year for the next 30 years, and if per capita GDP now is, say, $80,000, it would reach $183,182. But if it only grows 2.1% for 30 years, per capita GDP would be $149,232. That is about $34,000 less than if we grow 2.8%.

Per Capita Income After 100 and 200 Years At Various Annual Growth Rates (Starting With $1,000)

 Also see Scott Wolla on an Accounting Error about Imports and GDP by Pierre Lemieux.

Textbooks often show

GDP = C + I + G + (X – M)]

C = consumption spending
I = investment spending
G = government spending

with exports indicated by “X” and imports indicated by “M.” 

But

"the –M component is included as an accounting mechanism to ensure that the value of imported goods already included as personal consumption expenditures (C), gross private investment (I), or government purchases (G) is subtracted out."

GDP is supposed to measure the value production in the USA. If we spent $100 on imports, and that was on consumer goods, then the reported GDP would be $100 higher than it should be because we are measuring the value of domestic production and that $100 is already included in C. Subtracting M just gives the correct or accurate answer. Importing more does not reduce domestic production.

Also see Do imports subtract from GDP? from the St. Louis Fed.

Wednesday, July 24, 2024

Costco and Sam’s Club Aisles Are Full of Gen Z Shoppers

With food prices still high, shoppers look for ways to team up with roommates, neighbors and family

By Margot Amouyal of The WSJ. Excerpts:

"Young adults are battling sticker shock at the grocery store by supersizing their groceries. They are turning to bulk purchases, splitting their food costs with friends, roommates, family and neighbors.

Shoppers in their 20s and 30s are trying to fight higher prices by joining warehouse-store giants such as Costco and Sam’s Club. 

Generation Z shoppers represent the fastest-growing member group at Walmart-owned Sam’s Club"

"Memberships for shoppers ages 27 and under rose 63% over the past two fiscal years. Gen Z and millennials—customers 28 to 43—now make up a quarter of Sam’s Club members."

"they are drawn to the lower per-unit food costs"

"They also see the warehouse stores’ huge crates of tomato sauce and gargantuan packs of chicken as a way to divide and conquer."

"Almost four in 10 shoppers between the ages of 25 and 34 split more bulk groceries with friends, neighbors, roommates and family"

"A third of all people questioned in the survey said they shop this way."

"Americans spend an average of 11.2% of their disposable personal income on food, a number approaching highs not seen in three decades"

"The retailers don’t love membership sharing. Costco has on-site ID checks, and both Costco and Sam’s Club limit members to two guests per visit. But both have reported net sales increases this year."

Related posts:

Inflation is mentally taxing (2024)

Inflation is mentally taxing. Dealing with a straitened budget exacts a psychological toll as well as a financial one

Store Brands Are Filling Up More of Your Shopping Cart (2024) 

People are on the look out for cheaper alternatives due to inflation

Consumers Fed Up With Food Costs Are Ditching Big Brands (2024) 

One thing that I always talked about with inflation was that one of its costs was all the things we had to do to avoid it. Consumers are making 8% more trips to different retailers as inflation continues to upend household budgets. They are going to more stores to find lower prices. But it costs time to do that and probably more money on gas.

Are Americans Worrying Too Much About Inflation? Two opposing views (2024)

The Era of One-Stop Grocery Shopping Is Over (2024)

When workers were paid twice a day and given half-hour shopping breaks (Germany, 1923

By mid-1923 workers were being paid as often as three times a day. Their wives would meet them, take the money and rush to the shops to exchange it for goods. However, by this time, more and more often, shops were empty. Storekeepers could not obtain goods or could not do business fast enough to protect their cash receipts. Farmers refused to bring produce into the city in return for worthless paper. The requirements to calculate and recalculate commercial transactions in the billions and trillions made it practically impossible to do business in paper Marks

Monday, July 22, 2024

Life is full of tradeoffs: Will More SpaceX Launches Damage Natural Areas?

See SpaceX Seeks More Experimental Rocket Launches, Aiming for Mars: Company seeks federal approval to conduct up to 25 Starship flights annually, five times higher than what is currently permitted by Micah Maidenberg of The WSJ. Excerpts:

"SpaceX is pushing to sharply increase rocket launches in Texas as it races to demonstrate its new vehicle can fly as designed.

The company has proposed to launch Starship rockets up to 25 times annually from its complex east of Brownsville, Texas, according to the Federal Aviation Administration. SpaceX has permission to conduct up to five orbital flights there under a plan the agency approved in 2022. 

SpaceX’s latest plan will likely draw scrutiny from some residents and environmental groups, who have said launches and related operations damage natural areas. Repeated beach closures for Starship operations have also generated frustration.

Supporters of SpaceX, including many elected officials in southeast Texas, have lauded the company for generating jobs and economic opportunities. The rocket maker has been transforming a corner of the state near the Gulf of Mexico through its development of what it calls Starbase, home to a large Starship factory and other facilities."

"Stepping up Starship’s flight rate in Texas requires a new environmental assessment overseen by the FAA, which regulates commercial-space launches.

In 2022, the FAA required SpaceX to carry out dozens of steps to mitigate the effects of Starship launches. Environmental groups have said that effort wasn’t enough."

"During its first flight from Texas last year, the Starship booster destroyed the launchpad during liftoff, spraying debris over a 385-acre area and starting a fire. 

That damage generated criticism from environmental advocates and was folded into a lawsuit that several organizations filed against the FAA last year, claiming the agency failed to fully study and address the impact of Starship launches."

Related posts:

Life is full of tradeoffs: If we want to protect Hawaii's marine life and tuna fisheries we will have fewer rare minerals for defense applications 

Life is full of tradeoffs: If we want to keep gas prices low we might have to reduce sanctions on Russia (2024)

Life is full of tradeoffs: if we want more "big data" and artificial intelligence then we might have less green energy (2024)

Life is full of tradeoffs: if we want more nickel to make EV batteries we might have to use more coal (2024)

Life is full of tradeoffs: it costs money to keep chemicals out of our water systems (2024)

Life is full of tradeoffs: reaching net zero emissions by 2050 vs. the costs of the transition (2023) 

Life is full of tradeoffs: If we want more wind farms, we might have fewer jaguars & pumas and less water (2023)

Life is full of tradeoffs: we can preserve more natural & cultural treasures by giving up uranium that promotes cleaner energy & less energy dependence (2023) 

Life is full of tradeoffs: More Renewable Diesel Might Mean Higher Food Prices (2023) 

Life is full of tradeoffs: More wind power might mean more light pollution & noise (2023) 

Click here to see all the previous "Life is full of tradeoffs" posts including 18 not listed here

Saturday, July 20, 2024

The surprising link between science fiction and economic history

Originally posted in 2016.

By Sebastian Buckup. He is Head of Programming, Global Programming Group, Member of the Executive Committee, World Economic Forum. Today is National ScienceFiction Day. Excerpt: 

"Exactly 200 years ago, in 1816, a teen-aged girl called Mary Shelley began writing the story of Frankenstein in a villa in Cologny, a short walk from where the World Economic Forum now has its offices. Her ghoulish but subtle tale featured a scientist bringing a sentient, suffering creature to life from parts found in the “dissecting room and the slaughter-house".
“Frankenstein” was written at the end of the First Industrial Revolution, capturing the fears and squeamishness of a society going through massive transformations whilst making its first forays into surgery. The book took inspiration from earlier critics of the dawn of industrialisation, among them John Milton and Samuel Taylor Coleridge.

Today, Shelley’s Frankenstein is seen as the start of a genre, the first work of science fiction. By imaginatively combining the rigour of science with the freedom of fiction, the genre plays a big role in expressing the hopes and fears we project into our creations.

The best sci-fi stories mix two ingredients. The first is great science which sometimes leads to surprising accuracy: Jules Verne imagined a propeller-driven aircraft in the early 19th century, when balloons were the best that aviation had to offer. In the 1960s, Arthur C. Clarke envisioned the iPad, and Ray Bradbury the Mars landing. It may just be a matter of time until “Samantha”, the AI voice in Spike Jonze’s film Her, will be real, or until we bump into a version of “Ava”, the humanoid robot from Alex Garland’s “Ex Machina”.
 
The second ingredient is a keen understanding of contemporary hopes and fears. This is what makes these books and films great tools for dissecting the sentiments of an era. The two most successful sci-fi stories ever, George Lucas’ Star Wars and Gene Roddenberry’s Star Trek, are amongst the best examples of how pop culture combined perceptions of technological progress with contemporary hopes and fears."

Other history related posts:

MONKS, GENTS AND INDUSTRIALISTS: THE LONG-RUN IMPACT OF THE DISSOLUTION OF THE ENGLISH MONASTERIES 

Did Tea Drinking Cut Mortality Rates in England?

Both numeracy and literacy were invented in the service of finance and commerce

Pre-market societies could sometimes have alot of violence

Was 1800 (approximately) A Pivotal Year In Human History? Robert Fogel, Francis Fukuyama, And Deirdre McCloskey All Seem To Think So

Some History of Insurance

The surprising link between science fiction and economic history

What happened in some earlier U.S. trade Wars?  

Did the industrial revolution cause children to take on adult roles later and later? 

Were The Pilgrims Capitalists Or Socialists? 

Primitive communism: Marx’s idea that societies were naturally egalitarian and communal before farming is widely influential and quite wrong (plus Ruth Benedict on property rights)  

When workers were paid twice a day and given half-hour shopping breaks (Germany, 1923) 

In 1923, Germany printed money to pay workers who were told to stay at home  

The short history of global living conditions and why it matters that we know it

Friday, July 19, 2024

Religion and Growth

By Sascha O. Becker, Jared Rubin and Ludger Woessmann.

"Abstract:

We use the elements of a macroeconomic production function—physical capital, human capital, labor, and technology—together with standard growth models to frame the role of religion in economic growth. Unifying a growing literature, we argue that religion can enhance or impinge upon economic growth through all four elements because it shapes individual preferences, societal norms, and institutions. Religion affects physical capital accumulation by influencing thrift and financial development. It affects human capital through both religious and secular education. It affects population and labor by influencing work effort, fertility, and the demographic transition. And it affects total factor productivity by constraining or unleashing technological change and through rituals, legal institutions, political economy, and conflict. Synthesizing a disjoint literature in this way opens many
interesting directions for future research."

This reminds me of the book The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. See Protestant ethic from Britannica. Excerpt:

"Protestant ethic, in sociological theory, the value attached to hard work, thrift, and efficiency in one’s worldly calling, which, especially in the Calvinist view, were deemed signs of an individual’s election, or eternal salvation.

German sociologist Max Weber, in The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism (1904–05), held that the Protestant ethic was an important factor in the economic success of Protestant groups in the early stages of European capitalism"

The co-author of this paper is also the co-author the book How the World Became Rich: The Historical Origins of Economic Growth by Mark Koyama and Jared Rubin. They included Weber and the role of religion in their book.

Related posts:

Vatican Tells Catholics How to Make ‘Faith-Consistent’ Investments (2022)

Another Book Relates Religion to Economics (2007)

Can You Mix Economics With Religion? (2022) (The ancient Greeks sure thought you could. They had a god of commerce and a god of wealth.)

Does Economics Trump Religion (2022)

New Book Uses Economics to Analyze Religion (2006)

Should you invest according to religious guidelines? (2017)

Monday, July 15, 2024

Life is full of tradeoffs: If we want to protect Hawaii's marine life and tuna fisheries we will have fewer rare minerals for defense applications

See Hawaii Bans Deep-Sea Mining as U.S. Political Support Splits on Party Lines: Backing for ocean-floor extraction has largely come from Republicans amid a push to extract minerals for defense applications; Democrats are coming out against the practice by Yusuf Khan of The WSJ. Excerpts:

"Hawaii is banning deep-sea mining, as rifts along party lines begin to show in the U.S. over the practice following calls to extract rare minerals from the ocean floor for defense applications. 

On Monday, Hawaii’s Democratic governor, Josh Green, signed a bill into law banning seabed mining in the Pacific Ocean state’s territorial waters, to protect the region’s marine life and tuna fisheries"

"Sen. Chris Lee . . . said . . . “ it’s also about ensuring the sustainability of fishing, respecting cultural rights, and preventing harm to tourism"

"proponents argue that the practice diverts harm away from terrestrial resources, for example rainforests in Indonesia that are being deforested for nickel needed in steel, batteries and, increasingly, national security defense purposes."

"many Republican leaders have voiced support for deep-sea mining, saying that it would give the U.S. a new source of critical minerals that is outside of China’s control."  

"So far, the ISA (International Seabed Authority) has given 31 exploration contracts to prospective miners, including five Chinese contracts, but no exploitation contracts." 

Related posts: 

Life is full of tradeoffs: If we want to keep gas prices low we might have to reduce sanctions on Russia (2024)

Life is full of tradeoffs: if we want more "big data" and artificial intelligence then we might have less green energy (2024)

Life is full of tradeoffs: if we want more nickel to make EV batteries we might have to use more coal (2024)

Life is full of tradeoffs: it costs money to keep chemicals out of our water systems (2024)

Life is full of tradeoffs: reaching net zero emissions by 2050 vs. the costs of the transition (2023) 

Life is full of tradeoffs: If we want more wind farms, we might have fewer jaguars & pumas and less water (2023)

Life is full of tradeoffs: we can preserve more natural & cultural treasures by giving up uranium that promotes cleaner energy & less energy dependence (2023) 

Life is full of tradeoffs: More Renewable Diesel Might Mean Higher Food Prices (2023) 

Life is full of tradeoffs: More wind power might mean more light pollution & noise (2023)

Life is full of tradeoffs, west Texas wind power vs. the Air Force, landowners, ecotourists, astronomers, archeologists and conservationists (2023)

Life is full of tradeoffs: more houses to help the homeless vs. more trees (2023)

Life is full of tradeoffs: if we want more graphite for car batteries we might get more emissions in making it or raise humanitarian concerns (2023)

Life is full of tradeoffs: If we support American workers with trade restrictions it might mean more inflation (2023)

Life is full of tradeoffs, wind power vs. fishing edition (2022)

Life is full of tradeoffs, reducing animal cruelty vs. increasing worker safety (2022)

Life is full of tradeoffs: If we want more historic preservation we might have to give up some solar panels (2022) 

Life is full of tradeoffs: We can have more bison or we can preserve archaeological sites (2022)

Life is full of tradeoffs: Adding geothermal power could hurt the environment (2022)

Life is full of tradeoffs: sustainability vs. competition edition (2022)

Solar Power’s Land Grab Hits a Snag: Environmentalists: Mojave Desert residents say they support clean energy, but not giant projects, citing threat to tortoises and views (2021)

Life is full of tradeoffs, the case of federal renters assistance (2021)

Life Is Full Of Tradeoffs: If We Want To Do More To Fight Climate Change We May Have To Lower Tariffs On Solar Panels Which Might Put U.S. Firms Out Of Business (2021)

Tradeoffs and anti-trust policy (2019) 

Tradeoffs: More Goods And Services Might Mean Less Clean Air (2013)

The Recession Cleaned The Air, Another Example Of How Life Is Full Of Tradeoffs (2011)

Environmentalists vs. . . . other environmentalists? Or, are birds more important than clean, cheap energy? (2007)

More Proof That Tradeoffs Are Everywhere: Blind People Don't Like The New, Quiet Hybrid Cars (2007)

Saturday, July 13, 2024

License to Exclude: Black Barbers in Arkansas

By Tanner Corley, Wendy Lucas, and Marcus Witcher.

When I taught micro, I used a supplemental text, The Economics of Public Issues, by Roger Miller, Daniel Benjamin and Douglass North. They had a chapter titled  "Keeping the Competition Out."

In the 2018 (20th) edition they wrote:

"Thirty years ago, there were about eighty occupations  for which one or more state governments required a license. Today, there are over eleven hundred occupations that require a license in at least one state, ranging from secretaries in Georgia to wallpaper hangers in California. Roughly 30 percent of the U.S. labor force, about forty-eight million individuals, now belongs to a licensed profession."

Now the abstract from the article linked above

"Abstract

In the early twentieth century, predominantly white union barbers in Arkansas implemented voluntary regulations that dictated business practices to create a voluntary cartel. Black and other minority barbers who often had more success than white barbers prior to unionization tended to ignore these regulations, destabilizing the union’s cartel. Lacking a strong enforcement mechanism, white union members turned to the state to eliminate what they saw as unfair competition. By implementing a licensure law and creating the Board of Barber Examiners in 1937, established barbers were able to give themselves a stark advantage over future entrants into the profession. The law was detrimental to minority barbers. Black barbers failed to pass barber licensure exams at an equivalent rate as their white counterparts, and the number of Black barbers in Arkansas decreased significantly over the decade that the regulations were implemented. In making our assertions, we examine primary sources regarding the Journeymen Barber’s International Union of America, while also keeping in mind the data on pass rates, the composition of regulations, and exams that the Board of Barber Examiners implemented. Though scholars often assume that licensure laws harm minorities, we provide a detailed case study to support those claims."

Related post:

Licensing Laws Are Shutting Young People Out Of The Job Market (2016)

Thursday, July 11, 2024

The Seasonally Adjusted CPI Was down 0.056% in June (after being up only 0.0057% in May)

Which is almost no change. Some news stories said the CPI was down 0.1%. They rounded 0.056 to 0.1.

See Consumer Price Index for All Urban Consumers: All Items in U.S. City Average from FRED (Federal Reserve Economic Data) compiled by the Research Division at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis for data on the seasonally adjusted CPI.

That site shows a graph but if you click on the Download button you will get the actual numbers in Microsoft Excel.

The Consumer Price Index for All Urban Consumers: All Items in U.S. City Average (CPIAUCSL) was 313.049 in June and 313.225 in May. Since 313.049/313.225 = .9994, that means it was down 0.056% in June (since 1 - .9994 = .00056 which is 0.056% after you move the decimal two places to the right). If we had that every month for 12 months it would be down 0.68%. Which is also basically no change.

The last monthly decrease before now was the -0.006% change in July 2022.

It was 304.003 in June 2023. Since 313.049/304.003 = 1.03, that means it was up 3% over the last 12 months.

The non-seasonally adjusted CPI was 314.175 in June and 305.109 in June 2023. That was up 3%. So pretty close to the seasonally adjusted CPI. This is still above the Fed's target of 2.0% (although they prefer to use the Personal Consumption Expenditures Price Index which was 2.6% higher in May 2024 than May 2023).

For more information, see Inflation falls 0.1% in June from prior month, helping case for lower rates by Jeff Cox of CNBC (I wish that headline had said the CPI falls 0.1%, which is not the same thing as saying inflation falls 0.1%-If inflation fell 0.1% it would just mean that the rate of increase in prices was 0.1% lower than the previous month-prices still increased but not as much-in June prices actually fell). Excerpts:

"The monthly inflation rate dipped in June for the first time in more than four years, providing further cover for the Federal Reserve to start lowering interest rates later this year. [not sure why he says the first time in 4 years since the FRED site shows the CPI fell in July 2022-and, again, I wish he had said the CPI dipped not the inflation rate]

The consumer price index, a broad measure of costs for goods and services across the U.S. economy, declined 0.1% from May, putting the 12-month rate at 3%, around its lowest level in more than three years, the Labor Department reported Thursday. The all-items index rate fell from 3.3% in May, when it was flat on a monthly basis.

This was the first time since May 2020 that the monthly rate showed a decrease.

Excluding volatile food and energy costs, so-called core CPI increased 0.1% monthly and 3.3% from a year ago, compared with respective forecasts for 0.2% and 3.4%, according to the report from the Bureau of Labor Statistics.

The annual increase for the core rate was the smallest since April 2021."

The article also discusses what is going up and what is going on. There is a graph of the monthly year-over-year percent change in prices and core prices going back almost 3 years.

Other related links:

Consumer Price Index Data from 1913 to 2023

Personal Consumption Expenditures Price Index 

The Bureau of Labor Statistics makes seasonal adjustments. See Consumer Price Index Summary.

Wednesday, July 10, 2024

The Supply And Demand Game

I played it in each class I taught. A former colleague taught it to me many years ago. As far as I know, I use the game invented by Edward Chamberlin and refined by Vernon Smith. Click here to see the Lessons From the Supply and Demand Game. Or just read it all here.

Part 1: How the Game Works

The class played a game to earn extra credit points called the “The Supply and Demand Game.” Please also note, as far as I can tell, this game was invented by EH Chamberlin and later modified by Vernon Smith. I think I use the modified version. Several rounds of the game were played. In each round a student was either a buyer or a seller. Each student got a card at the beginning of a round that told them if they were a buyer or a seller. The object of the game was for buyers and sellers to make transactions with each other and maximize their surplus value.

Each buyer card had a maximum bid price on it which told the buyer the highest price they could pay in a transaction. The surplus value was the difference between the transaction price and the maximum bid price. For example, if a buyer’s card had a maximum bid price of $10 and they made a deal with a seller for $7.50, they got $2.50 in surplus value.

Each seller card had a minimum offer price on it which told the seller the lowest price they could accept in a transaction. If a seller had a minimum offer price of $5.00 and they made a deal with a buyer for $7.50, they got $2.50 in surplus value.

The more surplus value a student got, the more extra credit they got. In general, the object of the game was for buyers to make a deal for the lowest possible price and for sellers to make a deal for the highest possible price. Buyers and sellers walked around the class room looking for someone to make a deal with. There was no actual product for sale. Just buyers looking for sellers. After each round of the game, the prices of all the transactions were recorded. When the game was over, an average price per round and an average quantity (or number of transactions) was computed. Why was this important? Because the average price and quantity came very close to the equilibrium.

All of the buyer cards combine to make a demand curve that can be graphed and all of the seller cards combine to make a supply curve that can be graphed. If there are 24 students in the class, there will be 12 buyer cards and 12 seller cards. There will be exactly one card with each of the following maximum bid prices:

 

 $    4

 $    5

 $    6

 $    7

 $    8

 $    9

 $   10

 $   11

 $   12

 $   13

 $   14

 $   15

 

Since there is just one card with a maximum bid price of $15, only one buyer will be able to buy at that price (recall that the buyers have to buy at a price below their maximum bid price–I should say $14.99, but that is close enough to $15). So the quantity demanded (Qd) at $15 is going to be one since only one person can buy that high. At a price of $14, the Qd will be two because someone with a $15 card can buy at $14 and so can the person with the $14 card. Then the Qd at $13 is three. Below is the complete demand schedule:

 

Price

Qd

 $    4

12

 $    5

11

 $    6

10

 $    7

9

 $    8

8

 $    9

7

 $   10

6

 $   11

5

 $   12

4

 $   13

3

 $   14

2

 $   15

1

 

These numbers form the demand curve in the graph below.

We can do the same thing with supply. There will be exactly one card with each of the following  minimum offer prices:

 

 $    1

 $    2

 $    3

 $    4

 $    5

 $    6

 $    7

 $    8

 $    9

 $   10

 $   11

 $   12

 $   13

 $   14

 $   15

 

Since there is just one card with a minimum offer price of $1, only one seller will be able to sell at that price (recall that the sellers have to sell at a price above their minimum offer price–I should say $1.01, but that is close enough to $1). So the quantity supplied (Qs) at $1 is going to be one since only one person can sell that low. At a price of $2, the Qs will be two because someone with a $1 card can sell at $2 and so can the person with the $2 card. Then the Qs at $3 is three. Below is the complete supply schedule:

 

Price

Qs

 $    1

1

 $    2

2

 $    3

3

 $    4

4

 $    5

5

 $    6

6

 $    7

7

 $    8

8

 $    9

9

 $   10

10

 $   11

11

 $   12

12

 

These numbers form the demand curve in the graph below.


The supply and demand lines intersect at a price of $7.50 and a quantity of 7.50. When the game is played in class, the average price for the whole game and the average quantity (number of transactions) per round is always very close to these numbers. Why is this good?

Part 2: What the Game Teaches Us

Moral of the Story

Selfish, rational maximizers, acting without government intervention or regulation, arrived at an efficient price. An efficient price is one that creates no shortages and no surpluses. It is, therefore, socially optimal.

In the game, everyone was acting in their own self-interest. There were no rules telling people who they could or could not trade with or what price they had to charge.

So this is a demonstration of Adam Smith’s concept of the Invisible Hand which says that selfishness serves society. The players in the game acted based on their self-interest and the price and quantity that resulted were the best that could exist. Why?

By having a quantity at equilibrium, there is no surplus or shortage. Getting the price right helps in this process.

A  surplus is wasteful and inefficient because too much of a product is produced. Scarce resources are used to make goods that no one wants. A  shortage is wasteful and inefficient because too little of a product is being produced.  All of society’s wants or needs would not be met.

Now another way to get just the right amount produced would be for the government to set the price of each good. But how would they know what price to set? They would have to know the supply and demand curves for every good. This is very unlikely since it is a very difficult statistical problem to determine the supply and demand curves for just one good. And we know that the curves move all the time.

So if a government bureaucrat tried to set the price, they might set it too high (surplus results) or too low (shortage results). They would just as easily make the same mistakes if they tried to set the quanity.

Part 3-Conditions Necessary For the Unregulated Market to Achieve Socially Optimal Results

In the game, the class was a mini society and so was a perfect laboratory setting. The real world is not always so ideal. To have the unregulated market achieve the optimal results, certain conditions must be met. Sometimes they are not met in the real world.

1. Equal access to information-When one side has more information that the other, too little of the good is produced or offered for sale or the price is not at equilibrium.

In the game, if the buyers were required to show their maximum bid price to the sellers (while the sellers were not required to show their minimum offer price to the buyers), the sellers would have been able to get a higher price since they would have had an advantage. But then the market would not achieve the optimal result since the price would have been above equilibrium.

In the real world, we have markets without equal access to information. The used car market is an example. The seller knows more about the product that the buyer. If a seller has a car that is truly worth $1,000, no one will be willing to pay that much because potential customers will be suspicious due to their lack of knowledge. Perhaps they would offer only $750. So some car owners pull their cars off the market, not wanting to take less than it is worth. So fewer cars are traded (a below equilibrium quantity and therefore not optimal). Also, there is a danger that the only cars left will be “lemons.” They will be worth less than the price you pay (Economist George Ackerlof developed the “theory of lemons”).

The insurance market has this problem, too. The custormers don’t always tell their insurance company their bad habits (like smoking, riding a motor cycle without a helmut, etc.). So they don’t know how risky you are and therefore don’t know what price to charge you.

2. No monopolies-Monopolies charge a higher price than competitive markets. With monopolies, too litte is produced. Q is less than it should be (a below equilibrium quantity and therefore not optimal).

If just one student had been given all of the seller cards, they would have been a monopoly and would have raised the price above the normal equilibrium. In the real world, there are monopolies, like Microsoft and CPS.

3. No Externalities-Pollution is an example of an externality. When we drive, we, as individuals, do not consder the cost to others. Too much driving is produced (an above equilibrium quantity and therefore not optimal). Q is greater than it should be.

In the game, there were no externalities. No one was harmed by any transaction done by others. But in the real world we do have externalities.