Tuesday, May 19, 2020

Comparative Advantage

When I covered this recently in one of my classes, a student told me that when he took a high school economics class that the teacher said that there were cases where one country would not benefit from trading with another in a two good example.

This is just flat wrong, as I explain in the example below. If it takes country A less time to make both goods than country B, country A can still benefit by trading with country B.

From the OECD:

"The mathematician Stanislaw Ulam did not have a high opinion of the social sciences. He once challenged Paul Samuelson, Nobel laureate in economics, to name one social science proposition that was both true and non-trivial. Samuelson nominated comparative advantage: “That this idea is logically true need not be argued before a mathematician; that it is not trivial is attested by the thousands of important and intelligent men who have never been able to grasp the doctrine for themselves or to believe it after it was explained to them.”"

See Comparative advantage: Doing what you do best.

So here is a post from 2018.

Yesterday I posted a link to the new PBS series "First Civilizations" which had an interesting episode on trade. Last year was the 200th anniversary of David Ricardo's important idea called "comparative advantage." It explains how two nations can benefit from trade even if one country seems to be better at making all products than the other.

The Washington Post even had an article about it last year. It's the 200th anniversary of the most counterintuitive idea in the social sciences by Daniel W. Drezner, a professor of international politics at the Fletcher School of Law and Diplomacy at Tufts University.

Trade can benefit both sides. Otherwise, why make the trade? For example, if you have bread and no water and I have water and no bread, if I trade some water to you for some of your bread, we both gain or are better off.

It might seem like if one country is "better" at producing all goods than another, they have no room for trade. But even then, the seemingly more advanced country will still gain from trade.

Here is an example that comes from  David Ricardo himself. Comparative advantage is when you can produce a good at a lower opportunity cost than others face (in a two good example, it is impossible to have the comparative advantage in both goods).

Suppose it takes 40 labor hours to make a barrel of wine in England and 2 hours to make a yard of cloth. In Portugal, those numbers are 10 and 1, respectively. So it looks like Portugal is "better" at producing both goods since it takes them less time to make wine and less time to make cloth.

The labor hours numbers means that if England wants a barrel of wine, it would have to give up 20 yards of cloth (since 40/2 = 20-if you don't produce a barrel of wine, you save 40 hours of labor and you can make 20 yards of cloth in that time).

In Portugal, if you want to trade a barrel of wine, you can get 10 yards of cloth. Not spending 10 hours making wine allows them to make 10 yards of cloth.

So Portugal has the comparative advantage in wine since less cloth is given up there (10 yards) than in England (20 yards) for every one barrel of wine produced. That is a lower opportunity cost.

England would only give 1/20 a barrel of wine to make cloth while Portugal gives up 1/10 a barrel. England has the  comparative advantage in cloth.

How can the two countries gain from trade? What if England trades 15 yards of cloth to Portugal for 1 barrel of wine?

Both countries gain. England is better off since they only give up 15 yards of cloth to get that barrel of wine when normally they have to give up 20.

Portugal gets more cloth (15 yards instead of 10) for that 1 barrel of wine they trade. They are better off, too (even though it takes them less time to make each product than in England). 

No comments: